By: Bikal Dhungel
This was also a part of an assignment I wrote but I put here as well because it is relevant for developing countries and international development. Climate change is no more an isolated science, it has been incorporated to development because of its huge impact on development. The essay will highlight two instruments used to mitigate Green House Gas emissions, one being Carbon Tax ( in this essay a possible Global Carbon Tax ) and Carbon Emission Trading and compares them. The EU's emission trading system is used.
Introduction
Climate
Change is a global phenomenon which has already been one of the most
important issues in global political arena. It is a global issue
because no single country can escape the consequences caused by
global warming or avoid it. This can be in the form of rising sea
levels, changing landscapes, risk of drought, fire and floods,
stronger storms, emergence of more heat related illnesses, crop
failures, deaths of many species, ozone layer depletion etc
(NRDC,2008) which will place immense economic burden and to many
developing countries it is going to be a matter of life and death.
Hence, it has been generally agreed that countries in the whole world
have ‘common but differentiated responsibilities’ to tackle this
problem. However, the series of climate negotiations since the
previous decades have shown that, this is everything but a simple
negotiation between the nations. Developing Countries (DCs), Small
Island Nations and Developed Countries differ with their views about
the climate change itself, the ways to mitigate this and the extent
of cost bearing. The milestone of reducing the global warming by
limiting GHGs emissions was the Kyoto Protocol which set the target
of internationally binding treaty by its parties. After second
commitment, it was agreed to reduce at least 18% GHG emissions in the
period between 2013-2020 compared to the level of 1990 (UNFCCC-2014)
To reduce or limit the emissions, various policies were brought
either in country level or globally. Two of the important instruments
are ‘Carbon Trading Scheme’ and ‘(Global) Carbon Tax’. There
is no simple answer which one is better. Both Carbon Trading Scheme
and Carbon tax have advantages as well as drawbacks and as Global
Carbon Tax has not been implemented yet, it is unsure either it will
be a reality. The aim of this Essay is to compare both approaches
within the context of North-South divide.
The
Essay is structured as follows: Following the introduction, few
important terms will be defined. Arguments about the advantages and
drawbacks of both approaches will be dealt briefly followed by a
closer look into some scholarly evidences. Finally, a conclusion will
follow.
Definitions:
Carbon
Emission Trading: Aimed at reducing emission, Carbon Emission Trading
(hereafter only ETS) is the major element of Kyoto Protocol (Article
17) and allows countries to trade the spare emission certificates
they have based on market mechanisms (UNFCCC-2014). The fixed
emissions (also called ‘cap’) are divided into transferable unit
(like 20,000 permits for 2 tons of carbon) which can be used as
tradable commodity (Baumert,1998) .
The
European Union Emission Trading Scheme (EU ETS) – is one of the
many such regional schemes worldwide but a largest of its kind which
was adopted in 2003 to start operating in three phases, Phase I,
2003-2005 (learning by doing phase), Phase II from 2008-2012 and
Phase III after that, covering roughly half of whole EU CO2
emissions with 17% energy related CO2
emissions globally (Ellerman and Buchner 2007). The main objective of
this scheme is to reduce CO2
emissions and realise the goal targeted by Kyoto Protocol
significantly in the most cost-effective way (EC,2005). All 28 member
states plus Iceland, Norway and Liechtenstein are included in the
scheme and during the first year 2005, 320 million allowances worth
about 6.5 billion Euros were traded (World Bank,2012). About 5000
operators with combined 12,000 installations are the participants of
this scheme in mainly four sectors, energy, production or processing
of iron and steel, minerals like cement, gas etc pulp and paper
(Weishaar-2007) and recently to aviation sector. Other ETS exist in
Australia, New Zealand, South Korea is planning to implement it and
China is initiating a test phase in seven cities
(Goulder,Schein-2013)
Carbon
Tax: is simply a form of carbon pricing referring to a tax for the
level of carbon dioxide emission which can be expressed as 'Value per
tonne' CO2
equivalent (World Bank-2013). In other words, it is simply a tax for
consuming a fuel that emits carbon dioxide. This is also a method
that taxes the externality directly and makes sense both
environmentally and economically (Baumert-1998).
A
Global Carbon Tax (hereafter GCT): is simply a tax but with global
implementation. It has not been born yet but is a matter of huge
debate. Considering the global consequences of Climate Change with
huge burden placed on developing countries and the importance of
economic growth, North-South division about climate change exist.
Developing Countries (DCs) do not prefer the emission reduction
fearing economic growth which is vitally necessary to eradicate
poverty. Public intellectuals like Bjorn Lomborg and others are
calling poor countries 'too poor to be green' and environment is a
problem of tomorrow whereas poverty is of today. Other scholars call
for 'grow and clean up later' approach pointing to Environmental
Kuznets Curve1.
As a result there is a huge 'North-South' division regarding CO2
emission. Hence, it has been advocated that, only with a GCT with
financial support from industrial countries, DCs will play their role
to tackle climate change (Klein,Moehner-2007).
Additionally,
which instrument to choose to tackle the problem is still unsettled.
The viability of EU ETS is yet to be seen but if proven effective it
can be an example to the rest of the world. However, if successfully
implemented, tax is a ‘simple and flexible’ way to internalize
the GHG2
emission cost (Nordhaus-2007). Scholars opt for two models, 1) Where
only industrialized countries pay the tax and 2) where the burden is
shared globally. Model 1 might not be a feasible strategy as the
industrialized countries might not want to participate in such
schemes which will hamper the abatement strategies (Biccheti et
al-2010). However, with model 2, developing countries might not
participate. Still, an important advantage of uniform global tax is
that it will avoid the relocation of firms that opt to move to a
country with lower taxes (Cooper-2004). The advantages and
disadvantages of GCT are incorporated in the arguments below. While
arguing, it is also assumed that GCT is implemented globally.
The
aim of both instruments, ETS and CT is to reduce the CO2
emission (Goulder and Schein 2013). However, there is a huge debate
between which method is the best in terms of cost efficiency,
emission reduction etc. Especially in multi-national entities like
the European Union, it was everything but easy to reach an agreement
about which approach to embrace. There is huge difference between the
member states how they want to tackle the issue without hampering
their economic growth. During the nineties, the EU Commission itself
campaigned for carbon energy tax but failed to introduce it and
consequently, withdrew the proposal in 1997 (Convery-2009). When it
comes to global decision making process, the issue becomes more
complex. The following part will compare ETS and GCT approach.
- Administrative Costs: it would be simple and straightforward to administer GCT since it could be incorporated to current fuel-supply monitoring methods that already exist (Aldy,Stavins,2011). However, this argument is based on the fact that, tax would be set upstream3. Stavins (2007) mentions that, upstream scheme include about 2000 energy supply companies which should be regulated whereas the downstream scheme would involve millions of regulation points because even the emissions of every households should be taken into account. Hence, GCT is only advantageous in comparison to ETS if it would be set upstream.
- Emission Reduction: Under a ETS scheme, firms have an incentive to reduce the emission by switching to low emission technologies or at least investing in research and technology whereas in GCT, since there is only a rate of tax based on emission level, firms have less incentive to reduce emission. It does not guarantee a reduction and can cross the emission level beyond the limit set by environmental agreements (Goulder, Schein-2013). However, the evidence here is mixed. Despite the trading scheme, during the first phase of EU ETS, the emission level rose (Lang,2013) and then only decreased. The decrease can also be partly attributed to economic recession. On the other hand, Aldy and Stavins (2011) found that northern European countries were successful in reducing the greenhouse gas emission despite having a Carbon Tax scheme. Still, a longer time horizon is needed to check the viability of each scheme.
- Price Volatility/Uncertainty: In contrast to GCT, price volatility can be a serious issue for ETS. GCT could be set at a fixed rate but ETS is a market based mechanism where the price will fluctuate according to demand and supply levels. A lower price per ton of CO2 emission would de-incentivise the firms to invest in low emission technologies which can jeopardize the climate project. The allowance price in Phase II of EU ETS remained volatile. In early 2008, it was €20/tCO2 then increased to €22/tCO2 in the second half. Beginning of 2009, it fell to €13/tCO2 and fell further down to €10/tCO2 in mid-2011 (Laing et al,2013). Developing new technology require price stability and a long time. With lower cost per allowance, firms prefer to continue using carbon intense technology and can halt the development of green technologies. However, the fall of allowance prices can also be due to macroeconomic turbulences like economic recession which can cause a decline of production output. Any macroeconomic instability in the future is likely to cause the price to fall which will make the society worse off in terms of environmental goals. Hence, in ETS, price is uncertain and in GCT, emission level is uncertain.
Drawbacks
of Global Carbon Taxes (GCT).
Aldy
and Stavins (2011) suggest that all countries should impose and
enforce a uniform domestic tax. However, confusion arises how it
should be determined, based on per capita GDP or population or fossil
fuel production. Distributional equity is another issue that is
complex to solve.
As
the tax rate might vary between countries, Aldy and Pizer (2009)
mention that energy-intensive companies may relocate to a new place
where the tax is lower. Moreover, big companies also tend to lobby to
get exemption from the tax justifying with the competition they face
in the market. Contrary argument to this is, though firms could
relocate, greater amount of emission is caused by non-tradable
sector, (transportation, households etc) (Stavin,Aldy-2011) so,
solely from environmental point of view, it would have lower effect.
Under ETS, this problem might not arise.
Drawbacks
of Emission Trading Scheme (ETS)
Nordhaus
(2007) highlights the issue of governance capabilities in developing
countries where dictators or corrupt politicians/administrators could
tangle the carbon market 'undermining the legimacy of the process'.
Similarly, ETS can also lead to wealth transfers to OPEC countries as
they can manipulate the allowance scheme by exploiting their
advantage as oil monopolists by reducing the supply of oil, hence
raising the oil price until the price of allowance are zero
(Schein,Goulder 2013). In carbon tax scheme, such transfer will not
occur as the emission prices are exogenously set.
Information
asymmetry is possibly the most important disadvantage of ETS. As many
external factors also play role, it is extremely complex to regulate
the scheme. It is often the case that the regulators lack information
about companies marginal abatement cost schedules in order to
determine the set of emission quota that lead to the equality of
marginal abatement cost to set their own marginal cost
(Schein,Goulder-2013) (Aldy,Stavins-2011). Challenges of increasing
surplus of allowance remain due to reasons like economic crisis or
inefficient allocation from regulatory authorities which is likely to
depress the goal of emission reduction (EC,2005) Some analyses also
claim about the superiority of CT because of its ability to maintain
fair distribution of burden between firms and consumers which
preserves international competitiveness and avoid the problem of
emission offsets (Goulder,Schein 2013). With ETS, difficulties with
offsets is a major problem (Hansen,2009).
Evidences
As
advantages and disadvantages exist in both schemes, in this section
we will look at the evidences based on two main areas:
- Was the EU successful in reducing emission? - Ellerman and Buchner (2008) estimated that in Phase I, 120-300 MtCO2 abatement could be attributed to ETS. Delarue et al (2008) estimated an emission reduction of about 150MtCO2 in power sector. However, Declercq et al (2010) estimated a 150 MtCO2 reduction of emission as an impact of economic recession due to lower electricity demand and fuel prices but another study by Carbon Finance Institute (2009) highlights that 40% fall in 2008 emissions compared to the previous year can attributed to EU ETS.
- Was there more investment in Innovation and Technology ? - A survey of 800 manufacturing companies in six nations by Martin et al (2011) studied either firms have embraced lower carbon alternatives and taken measures for clean innovation. They found that majority of the companies have undertaken GHG saving measures and there have been some impact on investment and innovation. Calel and Dechezlepretre (2012) found that EU ETS encouraged innovation and investment in clean technologies in firms that were regulated compared to those who were not.
Evidences
of Global Carbon Tax
Global
Carbon Tax does not exist yet, so we cannot look for evidences but
regional or national schemes exist. Bruvol and Larsen found that in
Norway, despite having a very high Carbon Tax rate, the taxes
contributed only 2.3% of total emission reduction. Elgie (2014) found
that, in British Columbia, Canada, fuel use dropped by 16% compared
to Canada's Kyoto Target of 6% reduction in 20 years. The Carbon
emission also decreased in Australia. In Sweden and Denmark, carbon
tax led to the reduction of per capita emission by 9% and 15%
respectively from 1990 to 2006 (Breslow et al-2014). There is a gap
in literature about the investment in climate friendly technologies
and the effects on products and pricing under CT.
Conclusion
This
paper has compared Carbon Emission Trading and Global Carbon Tax as
measures to mitigate CO2
emission. Although Global Carbon Tax can be a successful tool to
reduce CO2
emission, challenges exist to bring it into life. The issue of
cost-bearing, the extent of cost and how the revenues are to be used
plays an important role to meet a consensus internationally. Even it
becomes a reality despite the challenges, the success of this scheme
is yet to be seen though it has generated positive results in
regional and national level. Differences between the two schemes are
generally on administrative costs, level of emission reduction, price
volatility, complications in implementation, information asymmetry,
wealth transfer, good governance etc.
As
the current CO2 emission was basically caused by industrialized
countries, DCs alone would not bear the cost. Neither they are likely
to sacrifice economic growth for the sake of climate change. But
still, developing countries face the consequences of climate change
over-proportionally. So, the issue can only be dealt collectively. It
is an obligation of industrialised countries to support DCs
financially and by other means for example the Clean Development
Mechanisms (CDMs) and the choice of an instrument (either ETS or GCT
or both in tandem) should be chosen based on cost-efficiency and long
term feasibility.
No comments:
Post a Comment